A
Q&A with co-architect of the Big Deal Jan Velterop follows this
introduction
The
scholarly communication system has been in serious difficulties for several
decades now, a problem generally referred to as the “serials crisis”. The nub
of the issue is that the price of scholarly journals has consistently risen faster
than the consumer price index. This has seen research libraries increasingly
struggle to meet the costs of subscribing to all the journals their researchers
need.
In
the early 1990s, publishers found themselves in a situation where every time they
increased the price of a journal they were confronted with a wave of
cancellations. In an attempt to recover the lost revenue they would raise the price
again, which simply triggered another round of cancellations.
Conscious
that their livelihood was under threat, publishers cast around for a way to
lock subscribers in, eventually coming up with what became known as the “Big
Deal”.
Academic Press Big Deal contract |
With
the Big Deal, libraries are asked not to subscribe to journals on a
title-by-title basis, but to a pre-determined bundle of electronic journals,
which they have to commit to for several years. Usually this bundle consists of
the publisher’s entire portfolio, which might include hundreds of titles.
The
attraction of the Big Deal for the publisher was that it promised to end the
annual cancellation cycle. For libraries it provided access to a much larger
number of titles for the same price as they had been paying for a smaller set —
so long as they took the entire bundle, and so long as they signed a multi-year
contract. For authors it provided a larger and more stable audience for their
articles.
The
Big Deal was pioneered in 1996 by Academic Press (now part of Elsevier), when it signed
a three-year licensing contract with the Higher Education Funding Council for
England (HEFCE). The
agreement meant that anyone working in a higher education (HE) institution in
the UK got free-at-the-point-of-use access to AP’s entire journal portfolio.
Moreover, since it was HEFCE that paid the bill (by means of top slicing), the
deal brought the additional benefit of easing the pressure on the budgets of hard-pressed
UK research libraries.
The default
After
some initial scepticism, other publishers began to offer their own Big Deals,
and the model had soon become the default way in which research libraries
acquired access to scholarly journals.
However,
while AP’s basic concept was copied, most subsequent Big Deals were signed not
with national funding bodies but with library consortia. And since the costs
were not top sliced, it meant that libraries had to fund their Big Deals from
their own budgets.
It
soon became evident therefore that the Big Deal had failed to address the fundamental
affordability problem that lay at the heart of the serials crisis. And as publishers’
journal portfolios got larger and larger as a result of industry consolidation,
the Big Deals began to devour an ever larger portion of a library’s budget. As
a consequence, the Big Deal gradually fell into disfavour, with librarians
complaining that, like any journal subscription model, the Big Deal is by its
very nature monopolistic, and it locks libraries into an expensive and
inflexible system that they can only extricate themselves from with great
difficulty.
Keen
to find an alternative approach, the research community began to take an
interest in Open Access (OA). If papers
were made freely available on the Internet, they reasoned, not only would
researchers have access to everything they needed, but self-archiving (or green OA as it later
became known) might ease the affordability problem, by enabling libraries to begin
to cancel some of their journal subscriptions. With this end in mind, advocates
of green OA called on researchers to put their papers on the web (and later into
institutional
repositories).
In
addition, a new breed of publishers — e.g. BioMed Central (BMC) and Public
Library of Science (PLoS) — entered
the market offering to make papers OA for researchers as a core part of the
publication process, on condition that they paid an article-processing charge (APC). This later became known as gold OA.
In
the belief that the pay-to-publish approach would lead to lower publishing
costs, libraries began to persuade researchers to embrace gold OA. And to help them
do this, they agreed to use some of their serials budget to join the various bulk
purchase “membership” schemes that OA publishers like BioMed Central and Springer began to
offer. These schemes bought the institution’s researchers the right to publish
in OA journals without having to pay on a per-article basis.
The
belief that OA publishing would be cheaper was based on two assumptions. First,
that electronic publishing was inherently less expensive than traditional print
publishing. Second, that it would impose price restraint on publishers. The thinking
behind the latter was this: With subscription publishing it is not the
researcher who pays the bill, but the librarian. Consequently, researchers do
not care what journals cost, but simply demand the titles they need regardless
of what the library will have to pay for them. Since their job is to service researchers’
information needs, librarians generally feel they have to pay up. In other
words, there is a disconnect at the heart of the subscription model.
Moreover,
since all the papers in a journal are unique, librarians are not in a position to
substitute an expensive title for a cheaper one. So there is huge pressure on libraries
to subscribe to every journal published in the various research fields their
institution plays a role in.
By
contrast, OA advocates argued, with author-pays OA the buying decision is made
by researchers themselves, not by an intermediary. And since authors are able
to publish in a variety of different journals, they can shop around (i.e. journals
are substitutable, and authors can — and will — make informed buying
decisions).
But
there was a fly in the ointment. Like the Big Deal, OA membership schemes are
purchased by librarian intermediaries, so the same disconnect that exists in
the subscription model often continues to exist with OA publishing. Membership
schemes also tend to push authors in the direction of those publishers that their
library has a publishing contract with, thus limiting choice.
In
addition, a growing number of universities are now setting up gold OA funds
which authors can turn to for a subvention when they want to publish in an OA
journal. Once again, the bill is paid by an intermediary, not by the author.
Importantly, the money does not come from the author’s own research budget, so
price is unlikely to be a deciding factor when an author is looking for an OA
journal in which to publish.
Priorities
Unsurprisingly,
as self-archiving took off subscription publishers soon concluded that it posed
a serious threat to their revenues. And they responded in two ways.
First,
they insisted on self-archiving embargoes. These require that researchers wait before
making a copy of their paper freely available on the Web — generally 12 months
or more.
Second,
they began to offer hybrid OA. This allows authors
to choose to have the papers they publish in subscription journals made OA — but
again on payment of an APC. While in theory hybrid OA is no different to gold
OA (they both make papers freely available on payment of an APC), it is generally
more expensive than pure gold OA. More significantly, hybrid OA allows
publishers to “double dip” — i.e. earn revenues from both APCs and
subscriptions.
As
OA publishing has developed, therefore, hopes that it will prove any more
likely to restrain prices than subscription publishing have begun to evaporate.
Moreover, to the frustration of advocates OA has grown very slowly. Today, only
around 24% of research papers worldwide are OA (35% in the UK), and growth is currently
running at just 1-2% a year.
We
should also note that — with the exception of biomedical fields — about four
times as many papers have been made OA by means of green OA as compared to gold.
The
above is important because, although green and gold OA have traditionally been
viewed as two components of a larger strategy, recent developments in the UK look
set to fundamentally alter that balance.
Specifically,
in July the UK Finch
Committee
published a report that contained a number of recommendations about scholarly
publishing. Most notably, it recommended that all publicly funded research in
the UK should be made freely available on an OA basis. However, rather than calling
for all varieties of OA to be adopted, Finch concluded that the main vehicle should
henceforth be author-pays OA — either in gold or hybrid journals.
As
a result, rather than reducing costs, Finch estimated that its proposal would
require an additional £50-60 million a year, £38m of which would be needed to
pay APCs.
Unsurprisingly,
many reacted to the Finch recommendations with dismay. One complaint was that the
additional costs would fall disproportionately on the shoulders of research-intensive
universities (notably the Russell Group).
Nevertheless,
the UK government accepted nearly all
the Finch recommendations, and Research Councils UK (RCUK) immediately published a new OA policy. This new
policy will require that all the papers resulting from research wholly or
partially funded by RCUK will have to be made OA. And, as directed by Finch,
RCUK will require that authors prioritise gold over green, with institutional
repositories relegated to the role of preservation and data archiving.
The
additional costs of this policy will be met by means of block grants from RCUK,
but the money will come out of the existing national research budget, so it
will not be new money. In addition, to placate the Russell Group the UK
government announced that it will
provide an extra £10m. This too will not be new money, but will come “out of ‘budget
flexibilities’ within the existing science budget”.
The
most vocal critics of Finch/RCUK, however, have been green OA advocates like Stevan Harnad, who anticipates
that subscription publishers (who still publish most peer-reviewed papers) will
respond to the new policy by lengthening their self-archiving embargoes to the
point where they are no longer compliant with RCUK’s policy, and tell authors
that they must pay for hybrid OA.
As
Harnad put it to me in
July, if one were a publisher one would naturally “offer to ‘allow’ your
authors to pay you for hybrid Gold OA (while continuing to collect your usual
subscription revenues) and, for good measure, you would ratchet up the Green OA
embargo length (up to the date your grand-children finished their university
education!) to make sure your authors pay you for hybrid gold rather than
picking the cost-free option that you fear might eventually pose a risk to your
subscription revenues!”
The
extent to which green OA will be superannuated remains to be seen. What we do
know is that, confronted with growing criticism, RCUK has felt the need to make
a number of clarifications (e.g. here and here).
Nevertheless, it has refused to change the wording of its policy, which clearly states that
researchers must prefer gold over green.
New Big Deal
What
this all means, suggests Harnad, is that publishers will now be able to provide
OA on their own terms, not on terms designed to protect the interests of the
research community. Essentially, the way is clear for publishers to port their
current revenues to the new OA environment, with no resolution of the underlying
affordability problem that has had the research community in its grips for so
long. In short, implicit in Finch/RCUK is a conviction that OA must have no
negative impact on publishers’ profits. With Finch/RCUK, says Harnad,
“publishers get their grotesquely inflated revenues, and the world gets gold OA
in exchange.”
It
is certainly strange that in recommending that gold be prioritised Finch argued
that green had failed — despite the fact that the majority of papers that are
OA today are OA as a result of self-archiving, not gold OA (see graph below), and despite there being no evidence that green OA has damaged publisher profits.
Harnad has long argued that the government should require all UK universities to mandate their researchers to self-archive, and then enforce compliance
Image courtesy of Yassine Gargouri |
Consequently,
he says, “RCUK would have been far better to adopt an effective
compliance-verification mechanism for its existing mandate than offer to pay
for gold.”
This
is important, he adds, not just because doing so would provide OA more quickly,
and not just because it would save money in the short-term, but because it would
force publishers to downsize their operations to the task of providing peer
review alone — which is all that is needed in a networked world — and so drive
down the long-term costs of scholarly publishing. And this would solve the unsustainable affordability problem.
As
it is, he says, the RCUK policy has simply paved the way for the reinvention of
the Big Deal. If you think about it, he says, the RCUK policy is the
BMC/Springer “membership” scheme, but at a national rather than an
institutional level. “The next step is national or even global ‘Big Deals’.”
He
adds, “Ever since the '90's one of the ‘options’ publishers have been gladly
offering is National or even Global ‘site licenses’: "You want everyone to have access to everything? Fine. We
publishers want that too. Let's agree a price and we'll give it to you!"
However,
not everyone believes that this is a bad thing — not least Jan Velterop, former AP
employee and one of the architects of the first Big Deal. “I don’t mind
‘green’,” says Velterop, “What I don’t see as remotely realistic is the idea
that ‘green’ should first force the publishers into submission before ‘gold’ is
being built up.”
Velterop
adds, “‘Gold’ is to a large degree developed by new entrants, not the
traditional publishers. It should be built up alongside ‘green’. That is more
likely to force the traditional publishers’ hands than ‘green’ alone.
Consequently,
he says, a national Big Deal is precisely what the patient requires today.
More
accurately, he adds, what is needed is a “New Big Deal”. Unlike the old Big
Deal, he explains, this would comprise both
“a national licensing agreement” that gave researchers free-at-the-point-of-use
access to all the papers still sitting behind subscription paywalls, plus a “national procurement service”.
The latter would buy free-at-the-point-of-use OA publishing services for UK
researchers, allowing them to publish in OA journals without having to foot the
bill themselves.
Transposed to a national level
Is
this the direction in which the UK is moving? After all, in the wake of Finch
researchers are being told that they must opt for author-pays OA (unless the
publisher offers neither hybrid nor pure gold), for which RCUK will provide
block grants.
In
addition, the UK government has promised an extra £10m to help research-intensive
universities meet their higher APC costs, and Finch has recommended that funds be
found to “extend and rationalise current licences to cover all institutions” —
which appears to be a proposal for a national licensing agreement.
The
question is whether at some point this could morph into Velterop’s New Big Deal
and, if it did, whether such an approach would solve the affordability problem.
Currently
the UK government is insisting that gold OA must be funded from the existing national
research budget. However, if the costs were at some point provided on a top-sliced
basis, the arrangement would look rather similar to the 1996 HEFCE/AP agreement
(although with an added OA element). This would certainly solve the
affordability problem — for universities, if not for taxpayers.
However,
that seems highly unlikely in today’s financially constrained environment. The
bad news for UK universities, therefore, would seem to be that the government
is herding them down a similar road to that taken by the research community in
1996, and the crippling affordability problem will simply be ported to the new
OA environment.
However,
Velterop disagrees that this would be the inevitable consequence of the “New Big
Deal” he envisages. If the UK were to adopt such a model, he says, the
inflationary forces characteristic of the Big Deal would not be
replicated.
While
conceding that buying decisions would still be taken by intermediaries rather
than individual authors (as assumed in the early model of author-pays OA), Velterop
argues that it would nevertheless be possible to restrain prices. Market mechanisms would
simply be transposed from the individual scientist level to the national level,
he says.
“It’s
not inflationary like the traditional subscription system, because of such a
market mechanism. That is an essential difference with a subscription system
for non-rivalrous journal literature: a market mechanism is what keeps
unwarranted inflationary price increases at bay.”
It
is not entirely clear to me how this would restrain prices more effectively than
the Big Deal. However, Velterop does add that it would be essential that any New
Big Deal was negotiated by professional negotiators, not by librarians.
“Individual
librarians' negotiation positions are hopeless,” he says. “Not just because the
skills are virtually non-existent … but also because their negotiating clout,
as compared to a nation-wide purchaser, is insignificant.”
I
explore these issues further with Velterop below.
The Interview begins …
Jan Velterop |
RP:
You were one of the architects of the so-called Big Deal. Speaking to me
last year you said that the objective had been to end the
cycle of journal cancellations that the serials crisis had triggered. By
selling large bundles of journals rather than single subscriptions, the Big
Deal offered libraries access to more journals in return for a commitment not
to cancel any of them for a set number of years. In introducing the Big Deal
you also hoped to persuade national funding bodies to pay the subscription costs
by means of “top-slicing”. Amongst other things, you felt that this would ease the
financial pressure on libraries. And this indeed is what you achieved with the
first Big Deal that Academic Press signed with HEFCE — a three-year licensing contract
that provided free-at-the-point-of-use access to all AP journals to anyone in
an UK HE institution. Subsequently, however, the Big Deal fell into disfavour,
with critics arguing that it is monopolistic and that it locks research
institutions into an expensive and inflexible system that they find very hard to
extract themselves from. Would you agree with that description?
JV: I’m not so sure that the Big Deal fell into disfavour. At
least it didn’t for a long time. What did fall into disfavour was the idea of
top-slicing, which was very unfortunate. It transpired that many librarians prefer
to pay more for less than have their budgets top-sliced.
I still think a national Big Deal
would have many advantages, both for the Higher Education sector as well as the
publishers. The HE-sector would have a much better negotiating position, both
the HE-sector and the publishers a much lower level of admin, and the
publishers a higher level of financial security. On a national scale, access to
scholarly literature would be an “infrastructural” provision.
RP: And
this would be flexible?
JV: Indeed,
not flexible, but flexibility is not a useful characteristic of an
infrastructural provision on a national scale and flexibility can be very
expensive.
But we have moved on, and
progressive insights (though not shared by everyone yet) have pointed us in the
direction of open access.
RP:
As you say, top-slicing fell out of favour, and subsequent Big Deals tended to
be negotiated with consortia of universities rather than national bodies. The classic
Big Deal, of course, is based on a journal subscription model. It is a license
to access large bundles of scholarly journals. One problem with this model is
that the person who uses the product is not the person who purchases it, so
there is a disconnect. Essentially, this means that it creates a market without
any effective mechanism to constrain prices; and it is this, critics argue, that
has allowed journal prices to constantly rise above inflation rates. Would you
agree?
JV: Yes, the subscription
model as applied in the academic world has the drawback that it's not the user
who pays. Neither in his role of reader, nor in his role of author. But that is
a very widespread problem with any common resource. Think of the roads, or
mail, or rail, or police, or schools, or hospitals.
The
“benefit principle” (only those who
actually make use of the provision pay) can only apply in a limited way, if at
all, for common provisions. There is a perennial tension between common
interests and the ego-system.
RP:
OA advocates have long argued that Open Access will resolve the subscription
market disconnect by placing the purchasing decision on the author, not the
library. That is what you have argued is it not?
JV: You must know the
adage “publish or perish”. It’s not “read or rot”. That’s for a reason. The
benefits of publishing research in peer-reviewed journals accrues to a (much)
larger degree to the authors than to the readers. Publications and their
citations are the coin of the academic realm with which tenure and research
grants are obtained. In a way, an article in a peer-reviewed journal is an “advertisement”
of a researcher’s scientific prowess.
One solution to the problem that the
users are not the payers is to introduce a “benefit principle” in the
subscription model, by allocating the cost of subscriptions to the academic
departments according to usage. This is unlikely to happen.
So a shift to an author-side payment
for the service of arranging peer review and publication is a logical one. And
it makes open access possible. Leaving the financial decision to the authors
(and their paymasters) is leaving the decision to the only party with a real
choice.
RP: Can you expand on this?
JV: Readers
— and the librarians who serve them — need access to everything in their
discipline (and often to neighbouring disciplines as well), so they have no
meaningful choice. And they certainly can’t subscribe to one journal because
it’s cheaper and avoid another one because it’s more expensive. Authors,
however, publish a given paper in only one journal, and more often than not
they have a real choice, at least to submit. This introduces market mechanisms
that are lacking in the subscription system.
Finch
RP:
As you know, in the wake of the recent Finch recommendations the UK government
has committed the UK to migrating its scholarly journal publishing from a subscription
model to author-pays OA publishing. This has been somewhat controversial, especially
amongst Russell Group universities, who complain that the cost burden of OA
will fall on them disproportionately.
JV: The real issue with the transition from the subscription
model to the paid “gold” OA model is the transition to a model based on the “benefit
principle”. It’s possibly not the best model, but the only one that makes OA
possible and sustainable. The “green” model is often portrayed as cheaper, but
that's only the case if the subscription model continues to be paid for. And
those costs need to be added to the “green” model, in my view.
Any transition from subscription to
OA is hampered by the fact that in one model the “research-consumption-intensive”
institutions pay more; in the other the “research-production-intensive” institutions.
They are rarely the same, but the difference is pretty much ironed out if
looked at on a large enough scale — a national one.
RP: You are saying that, in contrast to the subscription
system, gold OA provides a model based on the benefit principle — only those
(authors) who benefit pay. However, the process of transition is problematic?
JV: Indeed, I’m saying that. And what I’m saying, too, is that
the benefit principle is possibly not the best for academic knowledge sharing.
If we look at academic publishing as a whole, the money now used to pay for the
system via subscriptions, on the readers’ side, could be used to pay for the
system on the authors’ side. It comes pretty much from the same ultimate
source, after all.
As said, the issue is the distribution
of the burden on the scale of HE institutions. That’s why I advocate a national
deal; the problem doesn’t exist — or is at least very much less — on the scale
of entire countries.
The potential advantages of a system
based on payment for publication, rather than on payment for access, are
enormous: proportionality with the research effort, complete and full open
access (inclusive of reuse rights), and functioning market mechanisms that keep
prices in check.
RP:
As I understand it, UCL’s David Price would like to see a kind of Big Deal approach
used to help the transition to OA — what he calls a “true
national licence”. I think perhaps you do too? Commenting on the
interview I did with him you said, “It is very unfortunate that the UK
librarians killed a national licence, which was in place for the original Big
Deal between 1996 and 1999, under the auspices of HEFCE, on the grounds that it
meant top-slicing of their acquisition budgets and a threat to their autonomy.
They preferred to pay more for less as long as they kept their autonomy. The
idea of a national licence should be resurrected.” Would I be right in thinking
that you agree with Price?
JV: I definitely think an
arrangement on a national scale is the preferred solution. For “gold” OA it
would not be a “licence”, but essentially a contract for the
procurement of publishing services.
RP: I think the Finch Report includes a limited national
licensing proposal. As it puts it, “During the period of transition to open access
publishing worldwide, in order to maximise access in the HE and health sectors
to journals and articles produced by authors in the UK and from across the
world that are not accessible on open access terms, funds should be found to
extend and rationalise current licences to cover all the institutions in those
sectors”. Is this a similar (although more limited) model to the licensing
agreement that Academic Press had with HEFCE, or something else?
JV: In essence this certainly
looks like a similar model to the one originally envisioned — and implemented —
between Academic Press and HEFCE, except in those days open access wasn’t part
of the equation yet. Combined with a national contract for the procurement of
open access publishing services this could be a very good basis for a managed
transition that wouldn’t have to have the extra transition cost the Finch
report is assuming.
It
is very unfortunate that the phrase “funds should be found” is used. It really
should have been “ways should be found”. If done properly, and on a national
scale, IDEAL-like arrangements might be possible, covering all institutions in
the country, for no more, or even less, than is being paid now. Centralising
licences on a national level would give negotiating clout that is currently
sorely missing on the side of the research institutions and universities.
The
original idea of IDEAL was to make it resemble as closely a nation-wide
infrastructural provision for higher education as possible.
RP: So you believe that a national solution is
possible for OA too — a kind of BMC/Springer “membership” scheme, but on a
national rather than an institutional basis. In other words, where David Price calls
for a national licensing system to help the UK transition to OA (“For an agreed
amount, publishers allow access to their content by all sectors in society”, as
Price puts it), you
envisage a national procurement system for OA publishing. And you see this as a
long-term approach, not just a transitional mechanism. Is that correct?
JV: I do see it
as a possible long-term approach. I initiated the BMC membership scheme in my
time at BMC. The membership fee could be negotiated by a national procurement
body.
For
traditional publishers with hybrid options, such a membership and a national
licence could be combined. When I was at Springer we had such a combined
deal with The Netherlands for a few years. I don’t think it is still in
place, as, from what I understand, the librarians couldn’t reach consensus to
extend it. I am in no doubt that a truly national approach could have achieved
more lasting success.
Big Deal approach
RP: In order to placate the Russell Group
universities, on 7th September David Willetts announced that the UK
government would make a further £10 million available for research-intensive
universities to help pay for APCs. Does this not smack of a Big Deal approach?
JV: Honestly, I
don’t know what this smacks of. It is of course the case that not all
literature will be OA if Britain decides to go OA. On a world scale the same
tension exists between “research-consumption-intensive” countries and “research-production-intensive”
ones as exists between institutions. I think the £10 million is a
subsidy in recognition of the fact that Britain is a “research-production-intensive”
country that still needs to buy subscriptions even if it is fully OA itself.
RP: Well, I think the money is intended not for
subscriptions, but to pay APCs. The press release says, “The investment will
enable a number of research-intensive UK institutions to kick-start the process
of developing policies and setting up funds to meet the costs of article
processing charges (APCs).” You will know that one of the criticisms of the RCUK
OA policy is that it will encourage subscription publishers to offer hybrid OA
rather than convert to gold. Hybrid OA is generally more expensive than gold OA.
Moreover, argue critics, the policy will enable subscription publishers to earn
revenue both from APCs and from subscriptions — in other words to “double dip”.
Do you see this as a problem?
JV: If indeed the
author-side paid OA model introduces a market mechanism, hybrid journals can be
as expensive as they wish, but they won’t have any OA articles, since those
would go to cheaper journals. Criticism of pricing I can understand, but I'm
puzzled by the enmity towards the notion of a hybrid journal.
The
“double-dipping” argument is a red herring. There seems to be a notion that
subscription prices should be proportional to the number of articles in a
journal. How would that work? There are journals with 100 subscribers
(incredible as that sounds) and journals with thousands of subscribers. There
are journals that publish 25 articles a year and journals that publish 25 or
more articles a week.
The
cost, and indeed the revenue, of an individual article can only usefully — and
realistically — be expressed as an average, and then probably company-wide.
What would otherwise be the situation for a loss-making hybrid journal that
receives in one year 10% of its articles as gold, and the next year only 2%?
Impossible to work out. A subscription system is inherently lacking in
transparency.
If
journals should reduce their subscription price when they get a percentage of
papers paid for as gold, what should happen if they lose the same percentage
(for completely different reasons) of subscriptions?
What
if a journal which decided to go hybrid has published a steady amount of 50
articles a year for ages and all of a sudden attracts an extra 10 gold OA
articles? By how much should it reduce its subscription price?
You
see, not a problem that can be solved by simplistic approaches. If an article
is worth £2,000 to have published with OA in a full-OA journal, why is it not
worth the same £2,000 if published in a hybrid journal? Provided it’s with
CC-BY, which should be a strict requirement for paid gold OA in any event, full-OA
journal or hybrid journal. In my view, without CC-BY no article is worth the
label OA.
RP: Stevan Harnad argues that
publishers will respond to the RCUK policy not only by opting for hybrid OA
(rather than gold OA), but also by increasing the length of their self-archiving
embargoes. Since these longer embargo periods cease to be conformant with the
RCUK policy, green OA will no longer be a practical option for researchers.
This sidelining of green OA, Harnad says, will further allow publishers to
disproportionately increase their revenues — at the expense of the research community.
Is it that you do not agree with Harnad’s analysis, or is it that you do agree,
but do not see it as the problem that he does? Or maybe you see no way of
avoiding this?
JV: “Hybrid OA” doesn’t
exist. It is just “gold” OA. OA in a hybrid journal is the same as OA in a
fully OA journal for any given article. As was already made clear in the Bethesda Statement of 2003, “open access is a
property of individual works, not necessarily journals or publishers.” Stevan’s
scenario would equally apply if publishers would go fully OA.
Of
course, publishers could price themselves out of the market. And then they would
simply go under. The good thing about “gold” OA is that it introduces a market
mechanism. And that will keep prices down. And transparency optimal. Stevan’s
solution has characteristics of “having one’s cake and eating it”. It is saying
“we want open access but we want the dysfunctional market system of
subscriptions to survive, too”.
Green OA
RP: The most frequently voiced criticism of Finch
and the RCUK’s new OA policy is that they both relegate green OA to the minor
role of preservation, not of providing OA. Critics complain that this was a
result of lobbying by publishers. Is that your take?
JV: Perhaps it is. But I
think it is more likely that the Finch group has adopted the view that “gold”
is indeed the most straightforward, scalable (proportional to the research
effort and funding), and particularly because of this proportionality,
economically sustainable model. After all, the “green” model needs
subscriptions to be maintained, and the cost of those needs to be taken into
account when comparing what is financially the best option for the country.
What
I genuinely don't understand is the enthusiasm of the publishers for the “gold”
model (apart from the OA publishers, of course). The current per-article
revenues are, in my estimate, on average well over $5,000, whereas for APCs
it's well less than $3,000. This is revenues, not list-price.
Privately,
some publishers have expressed concern about “gold”. The ones I've talked to recently
much prefer “green” on the premise that the take-up is likely to be relatively
low, in spite of mandates, and chaotic, and difficult to find, with some
articles of a given journal available in OA and others not, and most only after
a delay.
To
be clear, I only talked to a few publishers of journals in the “hard” sciences,
and the situation may well be different in the humanities and social sciences.
RP: Indeed, and a recent Bernstein
Research report on Elsevier makes a similar point. If subscription
publishers are forced to migrate to OA, it says, “Our analysis shows that
Elsevier journal revenues would be under significant threat because the APCs it
would earn for many of its publications are unlikely to prove anywhere near
what the company needs to be revenue neutral, and it is difficult to envision
APCs that are high enough for its leading titles (the top 5/10%) to make up the
gap.” The Report goes on to ask, “So why was Elsevier supporting the Finch
report? We suspect that it viewed the alternative recommendation (a strong
backing of Green OA) as a much worse outcome. We are still wondering, however,
whether Elsevier is miscalculating … or is hoping that the OA movement will
stop at some declaration of good intentions or, in the worst case, at Dover.” Do
you think the subscription publishers have miscalculated?
JV: I believe the “gold” OA model is set to grow and grow.
Perhaps not as fast as many OA advocates — including myself — had expected, but
steadily nonetheless.
On the other hand we know that the
academic community is extraordinarily conservative. So subscriptions may
survive for quite a while still. The horizons of companies are often not very
distant, and miscalculations are the order of the day.
I think it is likely that the “gold”
OA model is mainly progressed by new players, and that traditional publishers will
see their market share eaten away.
Block grants
RP:
I suggested that David Price’s proposal for a national licence might be viewed
as a Big Deal, and I suggested that Willett’s additional money smacked of a Big
Deal approach. I am also wondering whether RCUK’s OA policy is not a Big Deal
of a kind too, particularly when viewed as a total package. As I understand it,
the arrangement currently proposed for the UK is that block grants will be
provided for universities to pay for APCs. Obviously, this consists of the
research community paying to publish papers, rather than for reading them, but
is it not reminiscent of the Big Deal model you pioneered in 1996 — a central funding
body agrees to fund the costs of scholarly communication for all UK research
institutions? In addition, extra funding will be found during the transition for
a national licensing scheme to extend access outside higher education, and in
order to placate research-intensive universities further cash is found to help
them pay their APCs — and all with top-sliced money. Is this not the Big Deal
by another name, although more of a patchwork Big Deal, and possibly a less effective
one for that?
JV: Block grants to
individual universities are not a national Big Deal. I would favour a deal that
says: “We, the UK, pay you, the publisher, an amount of X pounds, for which we
want for our HE-sector a) access to everything you publish; and b) Open Access
for every article published in your journals that originates in our HE
institutions.”
This
is not as simple as it might look, of course, but with historical data about
numbers of articles, subscriptions, finances, etc., and good rules and criteria
for periodical review of the arrangement, skilled negotiators would be able to
come to fair, comprehensive deals.
RP:
You said earlier of the Big Deal that we have moved on and that progressive
insights “have pointed us in the direction of open access”. Nevertheless, you say
you believe that there is a good argument for a national solution that includes
a “contract for the procurement of publishing services” combined with a
national licensing agreement, or Big Deal. Perhaps this is not so much a Big
Deal, as a New Deal. But how
would this provide what you called “market mechanisms that are lacking in the
subscription system”? Would it not be just as inflationary as the traditional
subscription system? Why, for instance, would authors care how much it cost to
publish their papers if someone else was paying the bill?
JV: Well, it would be a
Big Deal, but a New Big Deal, with different characteristics. National arrangements
would deal with Stevan’s problem of increasing APCs for hybrid journals. You
could retort that national deals actually remove healthy market mechanisms. But
that isn’t so.
The
market mechanism is just transposed to a national level from an individual
scientist level.
It’s
not inflationary like the traditional subscription system, because of such a market
mechanism. That is an essential difference with a subscription system for
non-rivalrous journal literature: a market mechanism is what keeps unwarranted
inflationary price increases at bay.
I
would think it wise to use some of Willetts’ £10 million transition fund to
hire some good negotiators and, on a national scale, progressively try to offset
subscription prices against OA fees so that the overall costs for the UK don't
increase.
Individual
librarians’ negotiation positions are hopeless. Not just because the skills are
virtually non-existent (of course I’m generalising and not doing justice here
to the exceptions), but also because their negotiating clout, as compared to a
nation-wide purchaser, is insignificant. If the whole country walks away from a
deal with a large publisher, the publisher is in trouble; if a university
librarian walks away, the librarian is in trouble.
RP:
So you are saying that rather than provide money for researchers to pay APCs,
RCUK would be better to hire a team of negotiators to agree new Big Deal
licences with publishers at a reduced price? If so, I guess this would be
similar to the recent RLUK
negotiations with Wiley and Elsevier, but on a truly national
basis, and with a publishing procurement component added. Other than that, you
think OA should be allowed to grow at its own speed?
JV: Just providing money
for APCs is not likely to progress things much beyond its current pace. And if
RLUK negotiations can achieve the results they have, you can imagine what a
truly national deal could do. Especially when New Big Deals include OA
provisions.
National procurement service
RP: Nevertheless, there seems to be a growing
consensus that the only way an effective wholesale transition to gold OA would
be possible would be if a global solution were adopted. That, of course, is
simply not possible. It is for that reason, perhaps, that we are seeing growing
calls for green OA which, as you pointed out, is somewhat chaotic in its
action, and develops only slowly. Above all, some OA advocates argue, green OA would
eventually force publishers to downsize and to innovate (Where Finch and RCUK simply
sets the traditional journal system in aspic). Do you have any sympathy for
this view?
JV: Yes, of course, a “wholesale”
transition would by definition be adopted globally. It wouldn’t be “wholesale”
otherwise. What you mean is probably “adopted worldwide simultaneously”. I
don’t buy the argument that a transition to “gold” OA were possible only if done
globally and simultaneously. As you say, that would render it impossible.
And
I don’t mind “green”. What I don’t see as remotely realistic is the idea that “green”
should first force the publishers into submission before “gold” is being built
up.
“Gold”
is to a large degree developed by new entrants, not the traditional publishers.
It should be built up alongside “green”. That is more likely to force the
traditional publishers’ hands than “green” alone.
“Green”,
especially with embargoes, risks setting the subscription system in aspic, to
borrow your phrase. The defence of traditional publishers is more likely to
consist of an increase of subscription prices to compensate for any loss of
subscribers as a result of “green”. And to refuse articles unless they come
with a full copyright transfer as well as to impose long embargoes.
RP: Assuming that its critics prove unable to
persuade RCUK to change its OA policy what kind of outcome do you expect we
will see? Will it be successful, and if it is, will this success end up having
cost more than it need have done?
JV: Not being able to
persuade RCUK to change its OA policy will be good for OA. And it will only
cost more if institutions fail to come together and collectively — or via a
national procurement service — negotiate what they pay for subscriptions in
order to be able to compensate for the cost of APCs.
Of
course there is the risk — however unlikely — that this happens only in the UK
and nowhere else in the world. In that case, cuts will have to be made in
subscriptions. What’s new?
RP: Finally, do you think that if the national
Big Deal model that you helped pioneer sixteen years ago had become the norm
(rather than morphing into a series of consortial deals) the scholarly
communication market might have developed differently than it has. If so, in
what ways might things be different today? Would Open Access have become the force it
has for instance?
JV: As always, it’s
difficult to speculate what would have happened. Open Access as we know it
might not have the urgency it now has, as access would be much wider anyway.
In
any case, a transition from payment for access to payment for the service of
arranging peer-review and publishing would have been a lot easier, in all
likelihood. The parties involved would have been of more equal strength. That’s
always a good starting point for reaching constructive consensus.
I’d
like to add one more comment, if you allow me. Open access is a means to an
end, not an end in itself. If scientific knowledge can be shared in other ways
as well, that should be done, too.
In
the natural sciences, for instance, the priorities seem to be more and more about
using and reusing data and data-like assertions from the literature
than about the possibilities for human reading — “ocular” access. Hence the
call for CC-BY, or “libre”
OA if you wish.
I
foresee a situation where a price is being paid for publishing services and “keeping the minutes
of science”, via APCs or even via subscriptions, whereas the
knowledge contained in publications is freely and openly shared. Now we see keeping
the record and knowledge sharing as being the same, but that need not be the
case in the future.
RP:
Ok, thank you for answering my questions.
From Fred Friend:
ReplyDeleteRichard Poynder has given us a valuable insight into the current UK OA situation through his interview with Jan Velterop, for whom I have held a great respect for many years.
The 1996 "big deal" to which Jan refers was called the Pilot Site Licence Initiative, and my memory is that it involved journals from Blackwell and IOPP as well as AP, although Jan certainly took the lead.
I disagree with one point Jan makes: that the librarians killed off PSLI because it was a threat to their autonomy. I was a member of the JISC committee monitoring PSLI and I cannot remember any antagonism from librarians.
In fact as Librarian of UCL at the time I wrote an article published in "Serials" in 1996 welcoming the Initiative (available at http://uksg.metapress.com/content/2p4k7ptt8g4cee2b/).
HEFCE commissioned a review of PSLI which must be available somewhere in the archives of HEFCE or JISC. I suspect that the Review did not say this, but my memory is that PSLI was not continued because of the very high cost, putting the funding of university institutions at risk if the Pilot was extended to a much broader group of publishers.
So far as I remember no negotiations took place, but extrapolating the cost from the relatively small number of journals into a comprehensive national deal was a frightening prospect.
So JISC went for the opt-in NESLI model instead of a true national licence – and the rest as they say is history.
Whether we really could get a national licence for a cost-effective price on subscriptions is once again open for investigation. My feeling is that where Jan’s proposal is more likely to be feasible is in a national procurement system for OA publishing.
I remember some discussions about such a model within JISC a few years ago, and the idea is similar to that behind SCOAP3, the difference being negotiating with publishers nationally instead of by subject group.
Publishers are very reluctant to negotiate collectively about any pricing mechanism, but if they were willing RCUK and JISC Collections could represent the academic side of the negotiations.
Fred Friend
Honorary Director Scholarly Communication UCL
http://www.friendofopenaccess.org.uk
Publisher Wheeling and Dealing: Open Access Via National and Global McNopoly?
ReplyDelete[part 1 of 2]
Excerpted from more extensive comments on the Poynder/Velterop Interview here and here.
JV: “a shift to an author-side payment for the service of arranging peer review and publication is a logical one”
The service of arranging peer review I understand.
But what’s the rest? What’s “Arranging publication”? Once a paper has been peer-reviewed, revised and accepted, what’s left for publishers to do (for a fee) that authors can’t do for free (by depositing the peer-reviewed, revised, accepted paper in their institutional repository)?
And how to get there, from here -- and at a fair price for just peer review alone? Publishers won’t unbundle, downsize and renounce revenue until there’s no more market for the extras and their costs – and Green OA is what will put paid to that market. Pre-emptive Gold payment, while subscriptions are still being paid, will not – and especially not hybrid Gold.
JV: “‘Hybrid OA’ doesn’t exist. It is just “gold” OA. OA in a hybrid journal is the same as OA in a fully OA journal for any given article.”
Gold OA is indeed Gold OA whether the journal is hybrid or pure (and whether the Gold is Gratis or CC-BY)
But “hybrid” does not refer to a kind of OA, it refers to a kind of journal: the kind that charges both subscriptions and (optionally) Gold OA fees.
That kind of journal certainly exists; and they certainly can and do double-dip. And that’s certainly an expensive way to get (Gratis) Gold OA.
And the Finch/RCUK policy will certainly encourage many if not all journals to go hybrid Gold, and publishers, to maximize their chances of making an extra 6% revenue from the UK, will in turn jack up their Green embargoes past RCUK’s permissible limits.
JV: “The “double-dipping” argument is a red herring. There's… a notion that subscription prices should be proportional to the number of articles in a journal. How would that work? There are journals with 100 subscribers… and… with thousands of subscribers [and] & 25 articles a year & 25 or more articles a week.”
Double-dipping is not about the number articles or subscribers a journal has, but about charging subscriptions and, in addition, charging, per article, for Gold OA. That has nothing to do with number of articles, journals or subscribers: It’s simply double-charging.
[part 1 of 2: continued below]
Publisher Wheeling and Dealing: Open Access Via National and Global McNopoly?
ReplyDelete[part 2 of 2]
Jan Velterop: “The cost, and… revenue, of an individual article can only usefully… be expressed as an average, and then probably company-wide. What would otherwise be the situation for a loss-making hybrid journal that receives in one year 10% of its articles as gold, and the next year only 2%? Impossible to work out. A subscription system is inherently lacking in transparency”
Nothing of the sort, and extremely simple, for a publisher who really does not want to double-dip, but to give all excess back as a rebate:
Count the total number of articles, N, and the total subscription revenue, S.
From that you get the revenue per article: S/N.
Hybrid Gold OA income is than added to that total revenue (say, at a fee of S/N per article).
That means that for k Gold OA articles, total hybrid journal revenue is S + kS/N.
And if the journal really wants to reduce subscriptions proportionately, at the end of the year, it simply sends a rebate to each subscribing institution:
Suppose there are U subscribing institutions. Each one gets a year-end rebate of kS/UN (regardless of the yearly value of k, S, U or N).
(Alternatively, if the journal wants to give back all of the rebate only to the institutions that actually paid for the extra Gold, don’t charge subscribing institutions for Gold OA at all: But that approach shows most clearly why and how this pre-emptive morphing scheme for a transition from subscriptions to hybrid Gold to pure Gold is unscaleable and unsustainable, hence incoherent. It is an Escher impossible figure, either way, because collective subscriptions/“memberships” – including McNopolies -- only make sense for co-bundled incoming content; for individual pieces of outgoing content the peer-review service costs must be paid by the individual piece. There are at least 20,000 research-active institutions on the planet and at least 25,000 peer-reviewed journals, publishing several million individual articles per year. No basis – or need --for a pre-emptive cartel/consortium McNopoly.)
JV: “If journals should reduce their subscription price when they get a percentage of papers paid for as gold, what should happen if they lose the same percentage (for completely different reasons) of subscriptions?”
Less Gold – the value of the year-end institutional rebate -- kS/UN – is less that year.
JV: “What if a journal which decided to go hybrid has published a steady amount of 50 articles a year for ages and all of a sudden attracts an extra 10 gold OA articles? By how much should it reduce its subscription price?”
By exactly10S/50U per subscribing institution U.
JV: “If an article is worth £2,000 to have published with OA in a full-OA journal, why is it not worth the same £2,000 if published in a hybrid journal?”
Simple answer: it’s not worth the price either way. Both prices are grotesquely inflated. No-fault peer review should cost about $100-200 per round…
Excerpted from more extensive comments on the Poynder/Velterop Interview here and here.