The message sparked a protracted
discussion, and eventually led to the publication of a book called Scholarly
Journals at the Crossroads: A Subversive Proposal for Electronic Publishing.
Today the Subversive Proposal is viewed
as one of the seminal texts of the open access movement.
To celebrate the 20th anniversary of the
Subversive Proposal, I emailed Harnad nine questions yesterday. These questions are published below, with Harnad’s answers attached.
Q&A
RP:
Today is the 20th anniversary of the Subversive Proposal, a 496-word
online message you posted to a mailing list on June 27th
1994 in which you called on researchers to make copies of all the papers they published
in scholarly journals freely available on the Internet. The message sparked a
heated online debate that later formed the basis of a
book. What stimulated you to make that posting, and why do you think it
attracted as much attention and disagreement as it did?
SH: Two things impelled me to do
it:
(1) I had been
editing a journal of open peer commentary
— Behavioral
and Brain Sciences — for 16 years at the time, and had always had the
feeling that the print-on-paper medium was not the
optimal medium for scholarly communication.
(2) I also had a
strong belief in the creative power of interactive written dialogue, which became even stronger with the advent of the
online medium. (I had dubbed this “scholarly skywriting.”)
For scholarly skywriting to work, it has to be
accessible online. But although I knew about the price of subscriptions and the
serials crisis at the time, that was not my primary motivation: open online access and interaction was
(and still is). (I explained this more fully in your 2007 interview.)
As to attention: I’d have much been much happier if it
had attracted action rather than just attention! The disagreement (which is
always welcome, and can even be creative) was about
the things we will go on to discuss further below: Green vs. Gold OA and, to a
lesser extent, Gratis vs. Libre OA.
RP:
Looking back, what contribution would you say the Subversive Proposal has made to
the development of the OA movement, which in fact really only became a movement
7 years later (in 2001), when the term open access was adopted at the meeting where
the Budapest Open Access Initiative was planned and articulated?
SH: I’m not sure. What I tried to urge
all scholars to do in 1994 (self-archive their journal articles) some had
already been doing for years (notably computer scientists in anonymous FTP archives since the 1980’s and physicists in arXiv since 1991), but
I’m not aware that the self-archiving rate increased appreciably after my
proposal. The proposal may have created a bit of a flurry, but it was a
notional flurry: it was not heeded when it came to actual action
(self-archiving).
At
the 2001 BOAI meeting, self-archiving got a name — it became “BOAI OA Strategy I”
(later dubbed “Green
OA”).
“BOAI
OA Strategy II” was OA journal publishing (“Gold OA”) and
that option (though it too was mentioned in the Subversive Proposal as the
likely end-game, after universal Green OA had prevailed) seems to have captured
people’s imaginations more than Green OA did. In fact, across the years since
1990 authors were providing little OA at all, though of the minority who were
providing OA, 2-3 times as many provided Green than Gold (and this is still true).
So,
again, I don’t see much practical
effect of the Subversive Proposal, either in 1994 or in the subsequent
half-decade. Nor did Green OA begin to come into its own when I commissioned
(and Rob Tansley created)
the first free software for creating Green OA institutional repositories in
2000. BOAI helped; but the first real sign of progress came with the outcome of
the 2004
UK Parliamentary Committee (which you phoned me in Barcelona to report,
Richard!). The committee recommended following the proposal — by me and others —
that UK research funders and universities should mandate (require) Green OA.
(The Committee only recommended some experimental support for Gold OA.) After
that, mandates
began to grow (though still very slowly).
RP:
As you note, the Subversive Proposal invited researchers to adopt what later
became known as Green OA. Shortly before
the BOAI meeting, Vitek Tracz founded the first open access publisher BioMedCentral, pioneering what became known as Gold OA. In the intervening years
there has been a frequently bitter debate about the respective merits of Green
and Gold OA. I realise you are an advocate for Green OA, but how would you
characterise the pros and cons of these two types of OA?
SH: Pros of Gold OA: (1) Gold OA
is immediate. (2) Gold OA can be made not just Gratis
OA (freely accessible online) but also Libre OA (freely accessible online
plus further re-use rights such as data-mining, re-mixing and re-publishing).
(3) Gold OA could solve the journal
affordability problem.
Cons of Gold OA: (1) Gold OA costs
extra money (author publication fees), over and above what institutions
already pay for subscriptions as long as subscription journals prevail (and
they still do). (2) Gold OA payment to publish risks a decline in journals’ quality
standards for acceptance (because journals are paid by authors to publish
their work, not by users to access their work) as long as subscription journals
prevail. (3) Gold OA payment cannot be mandated (required) as long as
subscription journals prevail. (4) Pre-Green Gold OA is vastly overpriced
(which is why I call it “Fool’s
Gold”) as long as subscription journals prevail.
Pros of Green OA: (1) Green OA
costs no extra money. (2) Green OA has no effect on journal quality standards.
(3) Green OA can be mandated (required).
(4) Green OA, once it is universally mandated by funders and institutions, can
allow journal subscriptions to be cancelled, inducing all journals to cut
obsolete costs (print edition, online edition, archiving, access-provision),
downsize to just the provision of peer review, and convert
to “Fair Gold” post-Green OA, paid for out of just a fraction of each
institution’s subscription cancellation savings.
Cons of Green OA: (1) Authors do
not self-archive spontaneously: like “publish or perish,” Green OA has to be
mandated by their institutions and funders. (2) Publishers can (and 40% do)
embargo Green OA self-archiving for 6-12 months or longer. (3) Not all Green OA mandates are effective:
it is important to adopt the most effective mandate model (which is the Liège/HEFCE mandate now also recommended after 10 years by BOAI-10).
You asked about the pro’s and con’s of Green and Gold
OA. I’ve tried to list all of them. Although the numbers look balanced, I think
anyone who gives it some thought will see that Green OA needs to be mandated
first and Fair Gold will be scaleable and sustainable and fair only after Green
OA has prevailed globally.
Mixed blessing?
RP:
I think it fair to say that publishers were initially highly resistant to open
access. Today, by contrast, I suspect no scholarly publisher would say that
they did not support it. However, publishers clearly prefer Gold OA. As an advocate for Green OA, would you say
that publisher support for OA has been a mixed blessing? If so, why?
SH: Maximizing the access, uptake,
usage, progress, productivity, applications
and impact of their publicly funded research output is a research community
(and tax-payer) matter, not a publishing industry matter. Publishers provide a
service to the research community (the management of peer review); the web has
made publishers’ other traditional service — access-provision — (along with its
costs) obsolete. Journal publishers already realize this, but the research community
has not yet realized it.
Journal
publishers earn a great deal of revenue from subscriptions — disproportionally
great; they know this too. But they would like to hold onto it for as long as
possible.
Consequently,
(some) journal publishers have embargoed Green OA to try to slow the growth of
OA and to try to redirect it to (Fool’s) Gold OA, priced on their own terms, so
as to sustain their current income levels, with the research community
double-paying (subscriptions plus Fool’s Gold OA fees) until there is a full
transition to Fool’s Gold on publishers’ terms. This route is not only pricey
but it is extremely slow, with precious research access, uptake, usage, progress,
productivity, applications and impact
being continuously lost during the wait.
Green
OA (universally mandated by research institutions and funders) could make the
transition to 100% Green OA happen almost overnight (just as I had hoped in
1994 that spontaneous self-archiving would do), and the transition to Fair Gold
OA (for peer review alone, all access-provision and archiving having been
offloaded onto the global network of institutional Green OA repositories) won’t
be far behind.
This
is what (some) publishers are desperately trying to forestall, by embargoing
Green OA and offering Fool’s Gold OA instead — under the pretext of supporting
OA. These days, publishers no longer have any choice but to profess support for
OA. But the research community has a choice about whether to provide OA in the
publishers’ slow and expensive Fool’s-Gold way, or to provide it themselves,
the Green way. Researchers could have
done it all spontaneously in 1994; let’s hope that their institutions and
funders will now see to it that providing Green OA is effectively mandated
before we lose yet another two decades of research access, uptake, usage, progress,
productivity, applications and impact
needlessly.
The HEFCE Policy
RP:
As I understand it, you believe that the recently announced UK HEFCE open
access policy has finally tipped the balance in favour of Green OA. There have
also been a number of other green OA policies announced in the past few months,
suggesting you may be right. However, as publishers are now actively promoting
pure or Hybrid Gold OA (which most if not all now offer I think) and funders
and research institutions have been busy creating gold OA funds, I have been
wondering if we might not see many of these green policies fulfilled by means
of pay-to-publish Gold OA. Would that in
your view be a good or a bad thing? Clearly it would increase the costs to the
research community, but it would have the merit of providing immediate OA, and
in many cases I assume it would also allow for reuse, so researchers would be
free to text and data mine the papers.
SH: The
UK HEFCE policy model for funders
— immediate
repository deposit required for eligibility for research evaluation,
irrespective of whether access to the deposit is made immediately OA or OA is
embargoed — together with its counterpart Liège policy model for
institutions, once they are adopted globally, will guarantee 100% OA in short
order (and will induce a transition to Fair Gold OA publishing not long after,
with all the re-use rights users need). (Meanwhile, embargoed Green OA deposits
are made almost-OA during any publisher embargo via the institutional
repository’s automated request-copy Button, with which any user can request and the author can
provide a copy for research purposes with one extra click each.)
But what (some) journal publishers would prefer is to
continue to hold research hostage to the tolls they dictate, whether via
subscriptions or via bloated Fool’s Gold OA
publishing fees. Offering Hybrid Gold OA together with Green OA embargoes — a Trojan Horse to penetrate the research community — would
be the optimal way for publishers to accomplish this: A subscription journal adopts a
Green OA embargo to prevent its authors from providing immediate Green OA, but,
by way of compensation, offers to sell authors immediate Fool’s Gold OA, for their
article only, for a fee. So institutions must keep on paying subscriptions, at
their current rates, until and unless all
authors find extra money from some other source (usually already-scarce
research funds) to pay the bloated Fool’s Gold fee: their research is held
hostage to subscriptions until the research community coughs up the same
inflated sums that they are paying now for subscriptions, but in the form of a
Fool’s Gold fee; until then, either double payment or no OA. (And publishers offer as a sop that they will continuously adjust their prices so that they do not earn more than they did from subscriptions).
What do I think? (not that it matters what I think): I
couldn’t care less whether 100% OA is reached via Green or Gold. What I care
about is that it is reached, and reached as soon as possible: it is already
vastly overdue, at great cost in lost research access, uptake, usage, progress,
productivity, applications and
impact (at least 20 years’ worth). I think the research community was extremely foolish not to provide
spontaneous Green OA in 1994. If they now prefer to double-pay for overpriced
Fool’s Gold OA in order to prop up the revenue streams to which publishers have
become accustomed, instead of just providing cost-free Green OA, that’s their own lookout. I am pushing for the universal
adoption of effective mandates that ensure that all researchers do provide OA, one
way or the other, now, and not another 20 years from now.
A
word about re-use
rights (“Libre OA”: data-mining, re-mixing and re-publishing): I’m all for them, just as I’m all for Fair-Gold
OA. I just don’t want them to get in the way of OA itself — already long
overdue — as Fool’s Gold OA has done. Hybrid Gold subscription publishers are
now dangling the prospect of Libre OA as an extra perk for paying for Fool’s
Gold (as if that further justified embargoing Green Gratis OA). If researchers
(or their funders or institutions) are able and willing to pay for this extra perk
now, fine. But the fact is that funds are short and most fields don’t need
Libre OA anywhere near as urgently as they need Gratis OA, whereas all fields
need Gratis OA — and we are still nowhere near 100% (or 75%, or even 50%)
Gratis OA yet.
So
let the institutional and funder immediate-deposit mandates be complied with in
any way that authors choose — cost-free Green or costly Gold — but let the
immediate-deposit mandates be immediately adopted and immediately complied
with, one way or the other.
Accessibility vs. Affordability
RP:
OA advocacy was initially driven by two different, but related, concerns. As
the people who have to pay the constantly-rising costs of journal
subscriptions, librarians viewed OA as an answer to what you refer to as the
affordability problem. That is, they supported OA because they assumed it would
lower the costs of scholarly communication. By contrast, researchers (initially
at least) viewed OA as a solution to the accessibility problem — i.e. they
wanted their work to be accessible to as many other researchers as possible.
But as librarians began to threaten journal cancelations the threat was that researchers
would have access to fewer and fewer scholarly journals, thereby reducing
accessibility. While we should not doubt that OA can solve the accessibility
problem, it is far from clear today that it will also resolve the affordability
problem — not least because publishers (and, it seems, many funders and
governments) believe that OA should have no negative impact on the revenues of scholarly
publishers. What are your current thoughts on this matter? Do you have any
concern about the affordability problem, or is it only a desire for greater
accessibility that motivates you?
SH: Many funders and governments? Not by my count. Only the UK’s RCUK, with its Finch Folly (now detoxified by HEFCE) and the well-intentioned but rather wilful Welcome Trust, as far as I know (with some echoed intentions — sans action — from Netherlands MP Sander Dekker).
But my sole interest in the journal affordability problem is inasmuch as it impinges on the research accessibility problem. Let me try to speak very directly, because there is a lot of double-talk on both sides, concerning OA:
But my sole interest in the journal affordability problem is inasmuch as it impinges on the research accessibility problem. Let me try to speak very directly, because there is a lot of double-talk on both sides, concerning OA:
(1) Some publishers
profess to be all for OA, but claim that unless subscriptions are protected
during any transition, they will be ruined, and both research publication and peer review will die. This is self-interested disinformation, used to lobby
against Green OA and Green OA mandates. It is these publishers’ current
inflated revenue streams that they are trying to protect, not research
publication, peer review or even the subscription model, let alone OA.
(2) Some
librarians profess to be for OA, but in practice, their pre-emptive threat
to cancel subscriptions as a journal’s Green OA percentage increases is an extremely
foolish policy, and against the interests of OA. Equally foolish and false,
however, is any assurance from librarians that once all journals’ articles have reached 100% immediate-OA (anarchically, via Green OA
mandates) they will not cancel their journals. (Of course they will! And
should! It’s the only
way to force journals to cut obsolete costs, downsize and convert to
Fair-Gold OA at a scaleable, sustainable price — paid for out of institutions’ windfall subscription cancellation
savings.)
(3) If governments
ignored publisher lobbying and did the arithmetic properly, they would immediately
see that the interests of publicly funded research vastly eclipse those of the
research publishing industry, and that the benefits of immediate Green OA
vastly outweigh the arguments of (some) publishers for a slow double-paid
transition to Fool’s Gold OA at their current asking prices, while holding
Green OA at bay with embargoes.
So
my reply to your question is that I care only about solving the research
accessibility problem, as soon as possible. (It is already grotesquely
overdue.) I believe the fastest and surest way to OA is to mandate
immediate-deposit Green OA. And I am confident that once that has generated
100% Green OA, thereby solving the accessibility problem, Fair-Gold OA will
follow, solving the affordability problem.
I
also believe it would be foolish to go for a direct transition to Fool’s Gold OA
instead. That would solve the accessibility problem, but certainly not the
affordability problem. Publishers would be getting paid as much as before. But I don’t care. At this point, the only thing that
matters is precious time, so much of it already having been needlessly wasted for two
decades. If 100% immediate-OA can be attained faster by throwing scarce funds
at Fool’s Gold OA during a double-paid transition period held in place by
embargoing Green OA, so be it — But I don’t believe for a moment that this would
indeed be the fastest way to reach 100% OA.
And
I hope that researchers, institutions and funders are not foolish enough to buy
it.
RP:
You often express surprise at the time it is taking for the world to wake up to
OA, which you have long argued is inevitable and optimal. Looking back, why do
you think it is taking so long for something inevitable and optimal to be
realised? And what in your view could the OA movement have done/still do to
speed the transition up? Or do the kind of changes required inevitably take a
very long time to achieve?
SH: I do not believe there is any
natural or social or psychological or neurological law that says the transition
to 100% OA had to take this long. I think the reasons it has been so slow are
multiple (and I’ve been enumerating them in the BOAI
self-archiving FAQ since 2002 as various forms of “Zeno’s
Paralysis”). If I had to pick the two most prevalent ones they would be (1)
groundless researcher fears of legal consequences if they self-archive and (2)
equally groundless researcher fears that self-archiving is a lot of work. Of
course, (3) publisher embargoes and (4) lobbying are designed specifically to stoke
such groundless fears.
The
cure for all this is for funders and institutions to adopt the HEFCE/Liège
immediate-deposit Green OA mandate model.
OA and the developing world
RP: OA advocates argue that open access has a great deal to offer the
developing world. In saying this, they point out that the high costs of
subscribing to scholarly journals means that the accessibility problem is far
greater in the global South, and so OA will be all the more beneficial. But if,
as increasingly seems likely, the dominant model for providing open access
becomes pay-to-publish Gold OA will researchers in the global South not find
that while they can read as much third-party research as they wish, they will
not be able to afford to publish their own work? I realise that OA advocates
dismiss this fear by pointing out that OA publishers offer APC waivers (or
reduced APCs) for researchers in the developing world. Researchers in the
developing world, however, respond that they do not want charity, not least
because charity can at any time be removed. Perhaps they have a point.
Initially, the non-profit OA publisher PLOS provided waivers on a
“no-questions-asked” basis. This was withdrawn in 2010. Then earlier this year
PLOS further tightened up its waiver
rules. Meanwhile, Elsevier’s APC
waiver policy is even more daunting, reading “If an author would like their
article to be published open access, but cannot afford these fees, then
individual waiver requests are considered on a case-by-case basis and may be
granted in cases of genuine need”. I am wondering who would relish going
cap-in-hand to Elsevier in order to make a case for “genuine need”? What are
your views on this?
SH: Pre-Green Fool’s Gold is
Fool’s Gold, any way you cut the cake; North, South, East or West. Right now,
any institution, in any country, that wants access to the refereed research
literature must pay subscriptions for as much of it as it can afford, and must
make do without access to the rest. Asking them to pay Gold OA fees now, on top of what
they are already paying for subscriptions that they can already ill afford would be
ludicrous, if it weren’t for all the publisher disinformation, lobbying, and embargoes — coupled with a goodly dose of “gold fever” in the research
community that is even more foolish than I was in imagining that the research
community would immediately do what was in its own best interests in response
to the Subversive Proposal in 1994.
So
my reply is, yes, Pre-Green Fool’s Gold is unscaleable, unsustainable, and
unfair, not just for the Developing World but for everyone who is not rolling
in excess cash. Let the Developing World (and everyone else) keep publishing in
the best journals they can, without paying an extra penny beyond what they are
already spending on subscriptions, and let the Developing World (and everyone
else) mandate immediate-deposit Green OA. Do that, and the optimal
and inevitable (and long overdue) will at long last be upon us. (Is that
yet another ill-fated subversive proposal, doomed to fail over the next 20
years?)
A Subversive Proposal for 2014
A Subversive Proposal for 2014
RP:
If you were composing the Subversive Proposal today how different would it be?
Would it be different? If so, would you care to rephrase it to fit today’s
environment? In other words, how would the Subversive Proposal look if written
for a 2014 audience (in less than 500 words)?
SH: Knowing now, in 2014, that
researchers won’t do it of their own accord, I would have addressed the
proposal instead to their institutions and funders, and in less than 200 words:
To maximize the access, uptake, usage, progress,
productivity, applications and impact of your publicly funded research output,
mandate (require) that the refereed, revised, accepted final draft of all
articles must be deposited in the author’s institutional repository immediately
upon acceptance for publication as a condition for research evaluation and
funding. If you allow an embargo on making the deposit OA (freely accessible to
all online), implement the automated almost-OA Button (and don’t let the
embargo exceed 6-12 months at most). This is called “Gratis Green OA.” Do not
pay for Gold OA journal publication fees (“Fool’s Gold”) until global Green OA
has made subscriptions unsustainable; then you can pay for Fair-Gold out of
your subscription cancellation savings. Fair-Gold will also be Libre OA (with
re-use rights such as data-mining, re-mixing and re-publishing). Ignore
publishers’ lobbying to the effect that Green OA will destroy peer-reviewed
journal publishing: it will re-vitalize it and save the research community a
lot of money while maximizing the access, uptake, usage, progress, productivity,
applications and impact of their research.
RP: Thanks for answering my questions. Readers
may also be interested in a 10-year review of the Subversive Proposal I wrote
in 2004 — Ten Years
After; and the 15-year review you wrote — The 1994 “Subversive
Proposal” at 15: A Critique.
1 comment:
For Paleontologists:
The 1994 Subversive Proposal at 15, 10 & 5
http://j.mp/subprop15
http://j.mp/subprop10
http://j.mp/subprop5
Post a Comment